Omni Calculator logo

Cobb-Douglas Production Function Calculator

Created by Marcin Manias
Reviewed by Dominik Czernia, PhD and Jack Bowater
Based on research by
Krugman P, Wells R. Economics, Fifth Edition; 2017
Last updated: Jun 05, 2023


The Cobb-Douglas production function calculator helps you calculate the total production of a product according to the Cobb-Douglas production function. Briefly, a production function shows the relationship between the output of goods and the combination of factors used to obtain them.

The Cobb-Douglas production function is a special form of the production function. It uses the relationship between capital and labor to calculate the number of goods produced. To learn more about the characteristics of the Cobb-Douglas production function, read the article below, where you can find more about the production function definition and production function equation. We also present the Cobb-Douglas production function formula; scroll down and check it out!

What is the Cobb-Douglas production function?

Development of this production function started in the 1920s when Paul Douglas calculated estimates for production factors for labor (workers) and capital (here in a broad sense: money, buildings, machines). He wanted to show how they relate to each other and express this relation as a mathematical function.

Charles Cobb suggested using an existing production function equation proposed by Kurt Wicksell as a base, which Douglas and Cobb improved and expanded upon. The results they got very closely reflected American macroeconomic data at the time.

Although accurate, economists criticized the results for using sparse data. Even when conducting small-scale research, you need a proper sample size to make your results statistically significant (see sample size calculator). It is even more critical when you want to try to estimate industry-wide macroeconomic theories.

Over the years, the theory was improved and expanded using US census data and proved accurate for other countries as well. Paul Douglas formally presented the results in 1947.

The Cobb-Douglas production function is known for being the first time a proper aggregate production function was estimated and developed to analyze whole branches of industry accurately. It was a cornerstone for macroeconomics and has been widely used, adopted, and improved since its inception. We can compare the importance of the Cobb-Douglas production function to macroeconomics to the importance of the Pythagorean theorem to math.

Production function formula (Cobb-Douglas)

The Cobb-Douglas production function formula for a single good with two factors of production is expressed as follows:

Y = A × Lᵝ × Kᵅ.

This production function equation is the basis of our Cobb-Douglas production function calculator, where:

  • YTotal production or output of goods;
  • ATotal factor productivity; it is a positive constant and is used to show the change in output that is not the result of main production factors;
  • LLabor input which indicates the total number of labor that went into production;
  • KCapital input which shows the quantity of capital that was used during production;
  • αOutput elasticity of capital; and
  • βOutput elasticity of labor.

Output elasticity is the responsiveness of total production quantities to changes in quantities of a production factor. It is a percentage change in total production resulting from a percentage change in a factor. The more capital or labor we use, the more goods we are going to get, but it is not a one-to-one conversion. It means that a 1 percent change in either factor would not result in a 1% change in total production but is rather dependent on the level of output elasticity associated with the factor (see percentage change calculator). Each of these values is a positive constant no bigger than 1 and is dependent on the level of available technology (0 ≤ α ≤ 1, 0 ≤ β ≤ 1).

In practice, they have to be smaller than 1 because a perfect production process does not exist – inefficiencies in labor and capital occur. Output elasticities can be found using historical production data for an industry. Suppose that output elasticity for labor – β is equal to 0.3. A 1% increase in labor would equal approximately a 0.3% increase in total production in that case.

Review the topic of percentages with our percentage calculator.

Cobb-Douglas production function characteristics

Now that you know a little more about the Cobb-Douglas production function, its history, and the main components, it is time to move on to the Cobb-Douglas production function characteristics:

  • Output elasticity, as mentioned above, is constant. It means that for a given Cobb-Douglas production function for a specific industry, the value of α (output elasticity of capital) and β (output elasticity of labor) should not change.

  • Marginal product represents additional quantities of output we get by increasing the amount of a production factor used by a unit. In the case of the Cobb-Douglas production function, the marginal product is positive and decreasing. It happens because output elasticity is positive. It is, however, smaller than one, so the Cobb-Douglas production function has diminishing marginal returns. It means that while increases in capital or labor will result in increased total production, each time, the increase will be a bit smaller than before.

  • Returns to scale represent the proportional change in output when the proportional change is the same in all factors. For the Cobb-Douglas production function, returns to scale are equal to output elasticities of both labor and capital: α + β.

If α + β = 1, you can say that the returns to scale are constant. It means that doubling the amount of both capital and labor would result in double the output. With the United States industry data available, this is what Paul Douglas observed when he was first establishing the function.

Let's see an example of such a case:

α is equal to 0.4, and β is equal to 0.6, therefore 0.4 + 0.6 = 1. So returns to scale are constant.

Let's assume that A is 2, our labor is 10, and capital is 15. Our production, in this case, would be:

Total production = 2 × 100.4 × 150.6 = 25.51

Doubling labor to 20 and capital to 30 would increase production to:

Total production = 2 × 200.4 × 300.6 = 51.02

Multiplying 25.51 × 2 = 51.02. Indeed, you can see that doubling the labor and capital resulted in doubling the production. If you are having trouble calculating labor and capital raised by alpha and beta check out our handy exponent calculator.

If α + β < 1, returns to scale are decreasing. The proportional change in factors will result in a smaller proportional change in output.

If α + β > 1, returns to scale are increasing. Likewise, the proportional change in factors will lead to a higher proportional change in output.

Cobb-Douglas production function example

In this example, you will see how our Cobb-Douglas production function calculator uses the data you provide to calculate the total production.

Let's say you want to calculate the total production of goods in a particular industry; for example, you are producing glass balls. For simplicity's sake, let's assume you only need workers and capital to do it. Let's assume you have 30 workers (labor). You also need units of capital, for example, $25. Total factor productivity is constant and equals 8 for your glass ball industry. Output elasticities are given and determined by the level of technology. Output elasticity of labor β is 0.4 and output elasticity of capital α equals 0.6. In that case, total production is calculated as follows:

Total production = 8 × 300.4 × 250.6 = 215.13

It means that using 30 workers and 25 dollars, you will be able to produce 215.13 units of product – in this case, glass balls.

Having different numbers of labor and capital while keeping total factor productivity and output elasticities the same allows you to calculate different levels of output depending on production factors for the same product – glass balls. For example, using 45 workers and 30 dollars would result in producing 282.26 glass balls:

Total production = 8 × 450.4 × 300.6 = 282.26

Providing more workers and money allows you to obtain higher production levels resulting in more glass balls produced than before.

Changing the total factor productivity or output elasticities constants in our production function example means that you will use a different Cobb-Douglas production function for a different industry – you will no longer be calculating output for glass balls, but, e.g., metal boxes instead. Of course, you don't have to do all those calculations by hand. Let our calculator do the work for you!

Our Cobb-Douglas production function calculator makes it easy to observe how total production changes depending on the changes in labor and capital. The reverse calculations are also possible. If you want to find out how much capital you need for a particular amount of total production, fill in other variables, and our calculator will find that value for you.

Marcin Manias
Total factor productivity (A)
Labor (L)
Output elasticity of labor (β)
Capital (K)
$
Output elasticity of capital (α)
Total production (Y)
Check out 35 similar macroeconomics calculators 💵
Buying powerCarry tradeComparative advantage… 32 more
People also viewed…

Alien civilization

The alien civilization calculator explores the existence of extraterrestrial civilizations by comparing two models: the Drake equation and the Astrobiological Copernican Limits👽

Car loan EMI

Use the car loan EMI calculator to estimate the monthly payments on your car loan.

Meat footprint

Check out the impact meat has on the environment and your health.

US income percentile

Our US income percentile calculator will help you to understand how your household income measures up when compared to the rest of the citizens in the United States.
Copyright by Omni Calculator sp. z o.o.
Privacy, Cookies & Terms of Service